Thursday, March 4, 2021

A review of the book The Sum of Us by Heather McGhee

 One of the mistakes that Karl Marx made was in predicting that the proletariats would rise up to supersede the bourgeois. The proletariats do not act as one body. Within the proletariat class, individuals make their own choices and move on their own timing. Some individuals aim to become part of the bourgeois. Some individuals have no ambitions about raising their own status or raising up their cohort. The possibilities for individuals are just so numerous and the class as a whole could never rise up to dominate the employers, land-owners and business elite.

McGhee does a splendid job of describing and narrating some individual choices made by white citizens in the United States who continue to confound analysts. She notes that white citizens do not seem to understand the economic and social costs they are creating for themselves, hyper-exemplified by the filling in of swimming pools when communities decided to prevent Blacks from attending those community venues rather than allowing integration. McGhee has realized the limits of research and numbers in convincing people to act in their own best interests. The neo-classical economics view of rational decision making to maximize utility has been dashed against American rocks. Philosophers, writers and researchers need to pursue some other understanding of American consumer/voter’s psychology. “…questions of belonging, competition, and status {are} questions that in this country keep returning to race.” (page 9) Joe Bageant in his 2008 book Deer Hunting with Jesus and in other essays added other insights on the ways so many white citizens make purchase decisions, will campaign, rally and vote in ways that are counter-productive to their own best interests. I can highly recommend Bageant to McGhee!

So very similar to Michelle Alexander’s historical prespective in The New Jim Crow, McGhee identifies that the plantation owners and employers of the 1600s antagonized the distrust between racial cultures in order to have those of European descent accept lower and lower pay, and to marginalize those of African and of Native American descent into enslavement. ”Whatever form these rationales took, colonizers shaped their racist ideologies to fit the bill. The motive was greed; cultivated hatred followed.” (p. 23) Surprisingly, she also finds a contemporary of Cassius M. Clay (1810 – 1903) to argue against the institution of slavery. While Clay is praised as an abolitionist, McGhee’s example in Hinton Rowan Helper was an outspoke racist. In 1857 Helper noted in his publications that the Northern states invested a multiple times more in public goods and community services, enhancing the life of Northern citizens. Comparing the number and character to those public goods for Southern states, Helper blamed the institution of slavery for sapping the desire to improve their communities with libraries, public schools, transportation improvements and other ventures. Since the plantation owners had free labor through enslavement, under-educated white citizens who did not participate civically, and their only markets were international, the Southern decision makers and politicians could ignore public improvement efforts.  McGhee draws to a conclusion that the mindset seems to have continued into the 21st century.

As a counter point, in the 1850s, Cassius M. Clay (as described by Ronald White, Jr. in the book A. Lincoln: A Biography) saw slavery as leading to a strange monopolization of valuable skills. When Clay returned from New England where he amassed his own fortune, he saw in Kentucky that the poor whites were being offered no marketable skills, the Black enslaved people were becoming the master craftsmen in all arts, and the plantation owners were ignorant of these ramifications from their dependency on slavery. Clay then marshalled his academic skills and found that the US Declaration of Independence needed to be revived and brought it’s democratic principles to the forefront in his arguments for abolition. Clay’s thinking and arguments impressed Abraham Lincoln so much that he too adopted the Declaration of Independence as the base for his arguments against spreading slavery into the territories west of the Mississippi River.

Unfortunately as her thesis question, McGhee might have better pursued multiple causes and multiple answers instead of early on in her book asking for one answer, “what is the stubborn belief that needs to shift now for us to make progress against inequality?” (page 10) There is not only one stubborn belief. According to the vote count for Trump in 2020, there may be as many as 75 million stubborn beliefs to identify and rectify.

She did find some value in the concept of a zero-sum game. Yes, according to the evidence presented by  Michelle Alexander and by McGhee, the early plantation owners did set up a belief system that persists today. If one class of the population gains, then another class is losing to the same degree. Academically and historically and statistically we can dismiss such an absolute view of trade-offs. Yet many of those white citizens can not dismiss it so easily. Many are still of the mindset that status can be more important than financial well-being. Many of McGhee’s stories demonstrate how whites will sacrifice financially/economically in the hopes of maintaining their perceived status above the racial minorities.

This zero-sum game means that if whites can not advance in some way for themselves, they must at least hold back the progress for the fuller society as a way of ensuring the racial minorities do not have greater opportunities to advance. Plus, McGhee’s evidence can be explained by a defensive nature to the actions of white individuals. More and more stubborn beliefs can be found and compound the complexity of these racial issues that McGhee uncovers throughout her book.

Meanwhile, I suggest that the Plutocrats and the extravagantly rich in the United States are still framing political problems as a zero-sum game to the conservative voters and to those economically struggling white citizens. The owning class still benefits from having the racial classes in clashing culturally, morally and physically against each other. Yet, that zero-sum could be turned against the Plutocrats. Our GDP has grown by less than 6 percent per year since 1985. For the foreseeable future, the GDP can not grow at any faster pace. There will be no exponential growth in the near-term. So our economic situation is a zero-sum game. If the top 10% of households take home 50% and then 52% and then 54% of the GDP in successive years, then the bottom 90% of households must be getting lower and lower proportions year after year. Based on such a seemingly-endless fear of losing out more and more every year, then the 90% can concentrate on the singular topic of income inequality and find ways to rectify that injustice.

Why is it an injustice?? According to McGhee and Michelle Alexander, the inequality in the Americas was started by plantation owners pitting racial groups against each other. Much of the racial strife we have experienced can be traced back to that zero-sum game invented by the earliest colonial Plutocrats. If we can place the racial groups on equal terms economically and remove the perceived threat for the white citizens, then possibly we can remove much of the future racial injustice. That is one facet of the injustice.

Another facet of the injustice is that the richest people can only claim such high incomes when they take advantage of and even exploit the employees who actually create the values that are sold by the businesses. I have identified this as Capillary Action in Micro-Economics. When a business hires an employee, that employee must create value in order to keep the employment. Specifically, each employee must over time create more value than the dollar value of one’s paycheck. If a particular employee is creating less value than one’s paycheck, then the business is losing money on that one employee. Every business owner knows that such a scenario is financially unstainable and such employees will need to be replaced or else the employer will go out of business. When employees coordinate with each other and equipment and inputs to create more value than the business’s costs, then the employer gets to accumulate the extra value as profits to be reinvested in the business or to be pocketed by the employer, owners and investors. That kind of advantage is acceptable because in a sense employees are taking advantage of the owners and investors who are facing the financial risks involved in running a business. The exploitation comes when employees are mistreated and denied fair compensation for the value they are creating, which leads to excessive earnings for owners and investors. Society could define what is excessive and exploitative, and how it rises to the level of injustice.

Eccentric incomes are also possible when customers and natural resources and financial systems are exploited. The Plutocrats usually are not being paid based on the value they create, but rather based upon their capital investments leveraging opportunities for exploitation.

In light of such injustices, the moral fight can be to #RegulateGreed with an income cap on all individuals. Or we might #RegulateGreed by setting an enforceable ratio so that top earners in any company can not earn more than say 300 times that of the lowest paid employee. If the top earners want to take home more money, then they will have to raise the pay of the lowest paid employees by the same proportion. Or other ideas can surface to #RegulateGreed. These types of direct actions to combat income inequality may eliminate the references to zero-sum games as employers and employees see their combined success as tied to each individual’s success.